Английская Википедия:Georgism

Материал из Онлайн справочника
Перейти к навигацииПерейти к поиску

Шаблон:Short description Шаблон:Redirect Шаблон:For Шаблон:More citations needed

Файл:FREE TRADE FREE LAND FREE MEN (Georgist campaign button).svg
Georgist campaign button from the 1890s in which the cat on the badge refers to a slogan "Do you see the cat?" to draw analogy to the land question[1]
Файл:Newcomer Koreisha Badge.svg
Shoshinsha mark emoji used by Georgists online due to its resemblance to a yellow and green shield.[2]

Шаблон:Economic systems sidebar

Georgism, also called in modern times Geoism,[3][4] and known historically as the single tax movement, is an economic ideology holding that people should own the value that they produce themselves, while the economic rent derived from land—including from all natural resources, the commons, and urban locations—should belong equally to all members of society.[5][6][7] Developed from the writings of American economist and social reformer Henry George, the Georgist paradigm seeks solutions to social and ecological problems, based on principles of land rights and public finance that attempt to integrate economic efficiency with social justice.[8][9]

Georgism is concerned with the distribution of economic rent caused by land ownership, natural monopolies, pollution rights, and control of the commons, including title of ownership for natural resources and other contrived privileges (e.g., intellectual property). Any natural resource which is inherently limited in supply can generate economic rent, but the classical and most significant example of land monopoly involves the extraction of common ground rent from valuable urban locations. Georgists argue that taxing economic rent is efficient, fair, and equitable. The main Georgist policy recommendation is a tax assessed on land value, arguing that revenues from a land value tax (LVT) can be used to reduce or eliminate existing taxes (such as on income, trade, or purchases) that are unfair and inefficient. Some Georgists also advocate for the return of surplus public revenue to the people by means of a basic income or citizen's dividend.

The concept of gaining public revenues mainly from land and natural resource privileges was widely popularized by Henry George through his first book, Progress and Poverty (1879). The philosophical basis of Georgism draws on earlier thinkers such as John Locke,[10] Baruch Spinoza[11] and Thomas Paine.[12] Economists from Adam Smith and David Ricardo, to Milton Friedman and Joseph Stiglitz, have observed that a public levy on land value does not cause economic inefficiency, unlike other taxes.[13][14] A land value tax also has progressive tax effects.[15][16] Advocates of land value taxes argue that they would reduce economic inequality, increase economic efficiency, remove incentives to under-utilize urban land and reduce property speculation.[17]

Georgist ideas were popular and influential during the late 19th and early 20th century.[18] Political parties, institutions and communities were founded based on Georgist principles during that time. Early devotees of Henry George's economic philosophy were often termed Single Taxers for their political goal of raising public revenue mainly or only from a land-value tax, although Georgists endorsed multiple forms of rent capture (e.g. seigniorage) as legitimate.[19] The term Georgism was invented later, and some prefer the term geoism as more generic.[20][21]

Main tenets

Шаблон:See also

Файл:Perfectly inelastic supply.svg
A supply and demand diagram showing the effects of land-value taxation in which burden of the tax is entirely on the landowner when the tax is implemented. The rental price of land does not change and there is no deadweight loss.

Henry George is best known for popularizing the argument that government should be funded by a tax on land rent rather than taxes on labor. George believed that although scientific experiments could not be performed in political economy, theories could be tested by comparing different societies with different conditions and by thought experiments about the effects of various factors.[22] Applying this method, he concluded that many of the problems that beset society, such as poverty, inequality, and economic booms and busts, could be attributed to the private ownership of the necessary resource: land rent. In his most celebrated book, Progress and Poverty, George argues that the appropriation of land rent for private use contributes to persistent poverty in spite of technological progress, and causes economies to exhibit a tendency toward boom-and-bust cycles. According to George, people justly own what they create, but natural opportunities and land belong equally to all.[6]

Шаблон:Quote George believed there was an important distinction between common and collective property.[23] Although equal rights to land might be achieved by nationalizing land and then leasing it to private users, George preferred taxing unimproved land value and leaving the control of land mostly in private hands. George's reasoning for leaving land in private control and slowly shifting to land value tax was that it would not penalize existing owners who had improved land and would also be less disruptive and controversial in a country where land titles have already been granted.

Georgists have observed that privately created wealth is socialized via the tax system (e.g., through income and sales tax), while socially created wealth in land values are privatized in the price of land titles and bank mortgages. The opposite would be the case if land rents replaced taxes on labor as the main source of public revenue; socially created wealth would become available for use by the community, while the fruits of labor would remain private.[24] According to Georgists, a land value tax can be considered a user fee instead of a tax, since it is related to the market value of socially created locational advantage, the privilege to exclude others from locations. Assets consisting of commodified privilege can be considered as wealth since they have exchange value, similar to taxi medallions.[25]Шаблон:Failed verification A land value tax, charging fees for exclusive use of land, as a means of raising public revenue is also a progressive tax tending to reduce economic inequality,[15][16] since it applies entirely to ownership of valuable land, which is correlated with income,[26] and there is generally no means by which landlords can shift the tax burden onto tenants or laborers. Landlords are unable to pass the tax on to tenants because the supply and demand of rented land is unchanged. Because the supply of land is perfectly inelastic, land rents depend on what tenants are prepared to pay, rather than on the expenses of landlords, and so the tax cannot be passed on to tenants.[27]

Economic properties

Шаблон:See also Шаблон:Economics sidebar Standard economic theory suggests that a land value tax would be extremely efficient—unlike other taxes, it does not reduce economic productivity.[17] Milton Friedman described Henry George's tax on unimproved value of land as the "least bad tax", since unlike other taxes, it would not impose an excess burden on economic activity (leading to zero or even negative "deadweight loss"); hence, a replacement of other more "distortionary" taxes with a land value tax would improve economic welfare.[28] As land value tax can improve the use of land and redirect investment toward productive, non-rent-seeking activities, it could even have a negative dead-weight loss that boosts productivity.[29] Because land value tax would apply to foreign land speculators, the Australian Treasury estimated that land value tax was unique in having a negative marginal excess burden, meaning that it would increase long-run living standards.[30]

It was Adam Smith who first noted the efficiency and distributional properties of a land value tax in his book The Wealth of Nations.[13] Шаблон:Blockquote

Benjamin Franklin and Winston Churchill made similar distributional and efficiency arguments for taxing land rents. They noted that the costs of taxes and the benefits of public spending always eventually apply to and enrich the owners of land. Therefore, they believed it would be best to defray public costs and recapture value of public spending by applying public charges directly to owners of land titles, rather than harming public welfare with taxes assessed against beneficial activities such as trade and labor.[31][32]

Henry George wrote that his plan for a high land value tax would cause people "to contribute to the public, not in proportion to what they produce ... but in proportion to the value of natural [common] opportunities that they hold [monopolize]". He went on to explain that "by taking for public use that value which attaches to land by reason of the growth and improvement of the community", it would, "make the holding of land unprofitable to the mere owner, and profitable only to the user".

A high land value tax would discourage speculators from holding valuable natural opportunities (like urban real estate) unused or only partially used. Henry George claimed this would have many benefits, including the reduction or elimination of tax burdens from poorer neighborhoods and agricultural districts; the elimination of a multiplicity of taxes and expensive obsolete government institutions; the elimination of corruption, fraud, and evasion with respect to the collection of taxes; the enablement of true free trade; the destruction of monopolies; the elevation of wages to the full value of labor; the transformation of labor-saving inventions into blessings for all; and the equitable distribution of comfort, leisure, and other advantages that are made possible by an advancing civilization.[33] In this way, the vulnerability that market economies have to credit bubbles and property manias would be reduced.[17]

Sources of economic rent and related policy interventions

Шаблон:See also Income flow resulting from payments for restricted access to natural opportunities or for contrived privileges over geographic regions is termed economic rent. Georgists argue that economic rent of land, legal privileges, and natural monopolies should accrue to the community, rather than private owners. In economics, "land" is everything that exists in nature independent of human activity. George explicitly included climate, soil, waterways, mineral deposits, laws/forces of nature, public ways, forests, oceans, air, and solar energy in the category of land.[34][35] While the philosophy of Georgism does not say anything definitive about specific policy interventions needed to address problems posed by various sources of economic rent, the common goal among modern Georgists is to capture and share (or reduce) rent from all sources of natural monopoly and legal privilege.[36][37]

Henry George shared the goal of modern Georgists to socialize or dismantle rent from all forms of land monopoly and legal privilege. However, George emphasized mainly his preferred policy known as land value tax, which targeted a particular form of unearned income known as ground rent. George emphasized ground-rent because basic locations were more valuable than other monopolies and everybody needed locations to survive, which he contrasted with the less significant streetcar and telegraph monopolies, which George also criticized. George likened the problem to a laborer traveling home who is waylaid by a series of highway robbers along the way, each who demand a small portion of the traveler's wages, and finally at the very end of the road waits a robber who demands all that the traveler has left. George reasoned that it made little difference to challenge the series of small robbers when the final robber remained to demand all that the common laborer had left.[38] George predicted that over time technological advancements would increase the frequency and importance of lesser monopolies, yet he expected that ground rent would remain dominant.[39] George even predicted that ground-rents would rise faster than wages and income to capital, a prediction that modern analysis has shown to be plausible, since the supply of land is fixed.[40]

Spatial rent is still the primary emphasis of Georgists because of its large value and the known dis-economies of misused land. However, there are other sources of rent that are theoretically analogous to ground-rent and are debated topics of Georgists. The following are some sources of economic rent.[41][42][43]

Where free competition is impossible, such as telegraphs, water, gas, and transportation, George wrote, "[S]uch business becomes a proper social function, which should be controlled and managed by and for the whole people concerned." Georgists were divided by this question of natural monopolies and often favored public ownership only of the rents from common rights-of-way, rather than public ownership of utility companies themselves.[33]

Georgism and environmental economics

The early conservationism of the Progressive Era was inspired partly by Henry George, and his influence extended for decades afterward.[54] Some ecological economists still support the Georgist policy of land value tax as a means of freeing or rewilding unused land and conserving nature by reducing urban sprawl.[55][56][57]

Pollution degrades the value of what Georgists consider to be commons. Because pollution is a negative contribution, a taking from the commons or a cost imposed on others, its value is economic rent, even when the polluter is not receiving an explicit income. Therefore, to the extent that society determines pollution to be harmful, most Georgists propose to limit pollution with taxation or quotas that capture the resulting rents for public use, restoration, or a citizen's dividend.[36][58][59]

Georgism is related to the school of ecological economics, since both propose market-based restrictions for pollution.[55][60] The schools are compatible in that they advocate using similar tools as part of a conservation strategy, but they emphasize different aspects. Conservation is the central issue of ecology, whereas economic rent is the central issue of geoism. Ecological economists might price pollution fines more conservatively to prevent inherently unquantifiable damage to the environment, whereas Georgists might emphasize mediation between conflicting interests and human rights.[37][61] Geolibertarianism, a market-oriented branch of Geoism, tends to take a direct stance against what it perceives as burdensome regulation and would like to see auctioned pollution quotas or taxes replace most command and control regulation.[62]

Since ecologists are primarily concerned with conservation, they tend to emphasize less the issue of equitably distributing scarcity/pollution rents, whereas Georgists insist that unearned income not accrue to those who hold title to natural assets and pollution privilege. To the extent that geoists recognize the effect of pollution or share conservationist values, they will agree with ecological economists about the need to limit pollution, but geoists will also insist that pollution rents generated from those conservation efforts do not accrue to polluters and are instead used for public purposes or to compensate those who suffer the negative effects of pollution. Ecological economists advocate similar pollution restrictions but, emphasizing conservation first, might be willing to grant private polluters the privilege to capture pollution rents. To the extent that ecological economists share the geoist view of social justice, they would advocate auctioning pollution quotas instead of giving them away for free.[55] This distinction can be seen in the difference between basic cap and trade and the geoist variation, cap and share, a proposal to auction temporary pollution permits, with rents going to the public, instead of giving pollution privilege away for free to existing polluters or selling perpetual permits.[63][64]

Revenue uses

The revenue can allow the reduction or elimination of taxes, greater public investment/spending, or the direct distribution of funds to citizens as a pension or basic income/citizen's dividend.[37][65][66]

In practice, the elimination of all other taxes implies a high land value tax, greater than any currently existing land tax. Introducing or increasing a land value tax would cause the purchase price of land to decrease. George did not believe landowners should be compensated and described the issue as being analogous to compensation for former slave owners. Other geoists disagree on the question of compensation; some advocate complete compensation while others endorse only enough compensation required to achieve Georgist reforms. Some geoists advocate compensation only for a net loss due to a shift of taxation to land value; most taxpayers would gain from the replacement of other taxes with a tax on land value. Historically, those who advocated for taxes on rent tax only great enough to replace other taxes were known as endorsers of single tax limited.

Synonyms and variants

Файл:Georgist Single Tax Poster.jpg
Georgist single tax poster published in The Public, a Chicago newspaper (Шаблон:Circa)

Most early advocacy groups described themselves as single taxers and George reluctantly accepted the single tax as an accurate name for his main political goal—the repeal of all unjust or inefficient taxes, to be replaced with a land value tax (LVT).

Some modern proponents are dissatisfied with the name Georgist. While Henry George was well known throughout his life, he has been largely forgotten by the public and the idea of a single tax of land predates him. Some now prefer the term geoism,[21][67] with geo (from Greek Шаблон:Lang Шаблон:Lang "earth, land") being the first compound of the name George < (Gr.) Шаблон:Lang < Шаблон:Lang "farmer" or Шаблон:Lang "agriculture, farming" < Шаблон:Lang + Шаблон:Lang "work"[68][69] deliberately ambiguous. The terms Earth Sharing,[70] geonomics[71] and geolibertarianism[72] are also used by some Georgists. These terms represent a difference of emphasis and sometimes real differences about how land rent should be spent (citizen's dividend or just replacing other taxes), but they all agree that land rent should be recovered from its private recipients.

Compulsory fines and fees related to land rents are the most common Georgist policies, but some geoists prefer voluntary value capture systems that rely on methods such as non-compulsory or self-assessed location value fees, community land trusts[73] and purchasing land value covenants.[74][75][76][77][78] Some geoists believe that partially compensating landowners is a politically expedient compromise necessary for achieving reform.[79][80] For similar reasons, others propose capturing only future land value increases, instead of all land rent.[81]

Some libertarians and minarchists take the position that limited social spending should be financed using Georgist concepts of rent value capture, but that not all land rent should be captured. Today, this relatively conservative adaptation is usually considered incompatible with true geolibertarianism, which requires that excess rents be gathered and then distributed back to residents. During Henry George's time, this restrained Georgist philosophy was known as "single tax limited", as opposed to "single tax unlimited." George disagreed with the limited interpretation, but he accepted its adherents (e.g., Thomas Shearman) as legitimate "single-taxers."[82]

Influence

Файл:Henry George.png
Henry George, whose writings and advocacy form the basis for Georgism

Georgist ideas heavily influenced the politics of the early 20th century. Political parties that were formed based on Georgist ideas include the Commonwealth Land Party in the United States, the Henry George Justice Party in Victoria, the Single Tax League in South Australia, and the Justice Party in Denmark.

In the United Kingdom, George's writings were praised by emerging socialist groups in 1890s such as the Independent Labour Party and the Fabian Society, which would each go on to help form the modern-day Labour Party.[83] The Liberal government included a land tax as part of several taxes in the 1909 People's Budget intended to redistribute wealth (including a progressively graded income tax and an increase of inheritance tax). This caused a political crisis that resulted indirectly in reform of the House of Lords. The budget was passed eventually—but without the land tax. In 1931, the minority Labour government passed a land value tax as part III of the 1931 Finance act. However, this was repealed in 1934 by the National Government before it could be implemented.

In Denmark, the Georgist Justice Party has previously been represented in Folketinget. It formed part of a centre-left government 1957–60 and was also represented in the European Parliament 1978–1979. The influence of Henry George has waned over time, but Georgist ideas still occasionally emerge in politics. For the United States 2004 presidential election, third-party presidential candidate Ralph Nader mentioned George in his policy statements.[84]

Economists still generally favor a land value tax.[85] Monetarist economist Milton Friedman publicly endorsed the Georgist land value tax as the "least bad tax".[14] Economist Joseph Stiglitz stated that: "Not only was Henry George correct that a tax on land is non-distortionary, but in an equilibrium society … tax on land raises just enough revenue to finance the (optimally chosen) level of government expenditure."[86] He dubbed this proposition the Henry George theorem.[87]

Communities

Файл:Everybody works but the vacant lot (cropped).jpg
1914 billboard citing Henry George in Rockford, Illinois

Several communities were initiated with Georgist principles during the height of the philosophy's popularity. Two such communities that still exist are Arden, Delaware, which was founded in 1900 by Frank Stephens and William Lightfoot Price, and Fairhope, Alabama, which was founded in 1894 under the auspices of the Fairhope Single Tax Corporation.[88] Some established communities in the United States also adopted Georgist tax policies. A Georgist in Houston, Texas, Joseph Jay "J.J." Pastoriza, promoted a Georgist club in that city established in 1890. Years later, in his capacity as a city alderman, he was selected to serve as Houston Tax Commissioner, and promulgated a "Houston Plan of Taxation" in 1912. Improvements to land and merchants' inventories were taxed at 25 percent of the appraised value, unimproved land was taxed at 70 percent of appraisal, and personal property was exempt. This was calculated using the Somers System.[89] This Georgist tax continued until 1915, when two courts struck it down as violating the Texas Constitution in 1915.[90] This quashed efforts in several other Texas cities towards implementing the Houston Plan: Beaumont, Corpus Christi, Galveston, San Antonio, and Waco.[91]

The German protectorate of the Kiautschou Bay concession in Jiaozhou Bay, China, fully implemented Georgist policy. Its sole source of government revenue was the land value tax of six percent which it levied in its territory. The German colonial empire had previously had economic problems with its African colonies caused by land speculation. One of the main reasons for using the land value tax in Jiaozhou Bay was to eliminate such speculation, which the policy achieved.[92] The colony existed as a German protectorate from 1898 until 1914, when seized by Japanese and British troops in World War I. In 1922, the territory was returned to the Republic of China.

Файл:Henry George School of Social Science 121 E30 jeh.jpg
Henry George School of Social Science in New York City

Georgist ideas were also adopted to some degree in Australia, Hong Kong, Singapore, South Africa, South Korea, and Taiwan. In these countries, governments still levy some type of land value tax, albeit with exemptions.[93] Many municipal governments of the United States depend on real-property tax as their main source of revenue, although such taxes are not Georgist as they generally include the value of buildings and other improvements. One exception is the town of Altoona, Pennsylvania, which for a time in the 21st century only taxed land value, phasing in the tax in 2002, relying on it entirely for tax revenue from 2011, and ending it 2017; the Financial Times noted that "Altoona is using LVT in a city where neither land nor buildings have much value".[94][95]

In 2023, Detroit mayor Mike Duggan and Michigan State Representative Stephanie Young proposed replacing existing property taxes with a land-value tax.[96] Following the 2008 Recession and city's 2013 bankruptcy, speculators bought cheap property, expecting to profit from the city's recovery. This plan to shift the cost of municipal services to owners of empty land, while exempting community gardens and parks, will require approval from the Michigan Legislature and Detroit City Council before being added as a ballot measure for Detroit residents.[2][97]

Institutes and organizations

Various organizations still exist that continue to promote the ideas of Henry George. According to The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, the periodical Land&Liberty, established in 1894, is "the longest-lived Georgist project in history".[98] Founded during the Great Depression in 1932, the Henry George School of Social Science in New York offers courses, sponsors seminars, and publishes research in the Georgist paradigm.[99] Also in the US, the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy was established in 1974 based on the writings of Henry George. It "seeks to improve the dialogue about urban development, the built environment, and tax policy in the United States and abroad".[100]

The Henry George Foundation continues to promote the ideas of Henry George in the United Kingdom.[101] The IU is an international umbrella organisation that brings together organizations worldwide that seek land-value tax reform.[102]

Reception

The economist Alfred Marshall believed that George's views in Progress and Poverty were dangerous, even predicting wars, terror, and economic destruction from the immediate implementation of its recommendations. Specifically, Marshall was upset about the idea of rapid change and the unfairness of not compensating existing landowners. In his lectures on Progress and Poverty, Marshall opposed George's position on compensation while fully endorsing his ultimate remedy. So far as land value tax moderately replaced other taxes and did not cause the price of land to fall, Marshall supported land value taxation on economic and moral grounds, suggesting that a three or four percent tax on land values would fit this condition. After implementing land taxes, governments would purchase future land values at discounted prices and take ownership after 100 years. Marshall asserted that this plan, which he strongly supported, would end the need for a tax collection department of government. For newly formed countries where land was not already private, Marshall advocated implementing George's economic proposal immediately.[103][104]

Karl Marx considered the single-tax platform as a regression from the transition to communism and referred to Georgism as "capitalism's last ditch".[105] Marx argued that, "The whole thing is ... simply an attempt, decked out with socialism, to save capitalist domination and indeed to establish it afresh on an even wider basis than its present one."[106] Marx also criticized the way land value tax theory emphasizes the value of land, arguing that George's "fundamental dogma is that everything would be all right if ground rent were paid to the state."[106]

Richard T. Ely agreed with the economic arguments for Georgism but believed that correcting the problem the way Henry George wanted, without compensation, was unjust to existing landowners. In explaining his position, Ely wrote, "If we have all made a mistake, should one party to the transaction alone bear the cost of the common blunder?"[107]

John R. Commons supported Georgist economics but opposed what he perceived as an environmentally and politically reckless tendency for advocates to rely on a one-size-fits-all approach to tax reform, specifically, the "single tax" framing. Commons concluded The Distribution of Wealth, with an estimate that "perhaps 95% of the total values represented by these millionaire [sic] fortunes is due to those investments classed as land values and natural monopolies and to competitive industries aided by such monopolies", and that "tax reform should seek to remove all burdens from capital and labour and impose them on monopolies." However, he criticized Georgists for failing to see that Henry George's anti-monopoly ideas must be implemented with a variety of policy tools. Commons wrote, "Trees do not grow into the sky—they would perish in a high wind; and a single truth, like a single tax, ends in its own destruction." Commons uses the natural soil fertility and value of forests as an example of this destruction, arguing that a tax on the in-situ value of those depletable natural resources can result in overuse or over-extraction. Instead, Commons recommends an income tax-based approach to forests similar to a modern Georgist severance tax.[108][109]

Other contemporaries such as Austrian economist Frank Fetter and neoclassical economist John Bates Clark argued that it was impractical to maintain the traditional distinction between land and capital and used this as a basis to attack Georgism. Mark Blaug, a specialist in the history of economic thought, credits Fetter and Clark with influencing mainstream economists to abandon the idea "that land is a unique factor of production and hence that there is any special need for a special theory of ground rent" claiming that "this is in fact the basis of all the attacks on Henry George by contemporary economists and certainly the fundamental reason why professional economists increasingly ignored him".[110]

Robert Solow endorsed the theory of Georgism, while being wary of the perceived injustice of expropriation. Solow stated that taxing away expected land rents "would have no semblance of fairness"; however, Georgism would be good to introduce where location values were not already privatized or if the transition could be phased in slowly.[111]

George has also been accused of exaggerating the importance of his "all-devouring rent thesis" in claiming that it is the primary cause of poverty and injustice in society.[112] George argued that the rent of land increased faster than wages for labor because the supply of land is fixed. Modern economists, including Ottmar Edenhofer have demonstrated that George's assertion is plausible but was more likely to be true during George's time than now.[40]

An early criticism of Georgism was that it would generate too much public revenue and result in unwanted growth of government, but later critics argued that it would not generate enough income to cover government spending. Joseph Schumpeter concluded his analysis of Georgism by stating that, "It is not economically unsound, except that it involves an unwarranted optimism concerning the yield of such a tax." Economists who study land conclude that Schumpeter's criticism is unwarranted because the rental yield from land is likely much greater than what modern critics such as Paul Krugman suppose.[113] Krugman agrees that land value taxation is the best means of raising public revenue but asserts that increased spending has rendered land rent insufficient to fully fund government.[114] Georgists have responded by citing studies and analyses implying that land values of nations like the United States, the United Kingdom and Australia are more than sufficient to fund all levels of government.[115][116][117][118][119][120][121]

Anarcho-capitalist political philosopher and economist Murray Rothbard criticized Georgism in Man, Economy, and State as being philosophically incongruent with subjective value theory, and further stating that land is irrelevant in the factors of production, trade, and price systems,[122] but this critique is seen by some, including other opponents of Georgism, as relying on false assumptions and flawed reasoning.[123]

Austrian economist Friedrich Hayek credited early enthusiasm for Henry George with developing his interest in economics. Later, Hayek said that the theory of Georgism would be very strong if assessment challenges did not result in unfair outcomes, but he believed that they would.[124]

Lists of Georgists

Шаблон:Columns-start

Economists

Шаблон:Column

Heads of government

Шаблон:Column

Other political figures

Шаблон:Columns-end Шаблон:Columns-start

Activists

Шаблон:Column

Authors

Шаблон:Column

Journalists

Шаблон:Columns-end Шаблон:Columns-start

Artists

Шаблон:Column

Philosophers

Шаблон:Column

Others

Шаблон:Columns-end

See also

Шаблон:Cols

Шаблон:Colend

References

Шаблон:Reflist

External links

Шаблон:Property navbox Шаблон:Schools of economic thought

  1. Шаблон:Cite web
  2. 2,0 2,1 Шаблон:Cite news
  3. Шаблон:Cite web
  4. Шаблон:Cite web
  5. Шаблон:Cite web
  6. 6,0 6,1 Шаблон:Cite journal
  7. Шаблон:Cite web
  8. Шаблон:Cite book
  9. Hudson, Michael; Feder, Kris; and Miller, George James (1994). A Philosophy for a Fair Society Шаблон:Webarchive. Shepheard-Walwyn, London. Шаблон:ISBN.
  10. Шаблон:Cite web
  11. Шаблон:Cite web
  12. Agrarian Justice, Wikisource edition, paragraph 12
  13. 13,0 13,1 Шаблон:Cite book
  14. 14,0 14,1 Шаблон:Cite book
  15. 15,0 15,1 Шаблон:Cite book
  16. 16,0 16,1 Шаблон:Cite journal
  17. 17,0 17,1 17,2 Шаблон:Cite book
  18. The Forgotten Idea That Shaped Great U.S. Cities by Mason Gaffney & Rich Nymoen, Commons magazine, October 17, 2013.
  19. Шаблон:Cite web
  20. Шаблон:Cite web
  21. 21,0 21,1 Шаблон:Cite journal
  22. Шаблон:Cite web
  23. Шаблон:Cite web
  24. Шаблон:Cite web
  25. Шаблон:Cite news
  26. Шаблон:Cite journalШаблон:Dead linkШаблон:Cbignore
  27. Adam Smith, The Wealth of Nations Book V, Chapter 2, Part 2, Article I: Taxes upon the Rent of Houses
  28. Foldvary, Fred E. "Geo-Rent: A Plea to Public Economists". Econ Journal Watch (April 2005)[1]
  29. Шаблон:Cite webШаблон:Cbignore
  30. Шаблон:Cite web
  31. Шаблон:Cite book
  32. Шаблон:Cite book
  33. 33,0 33,1 Шаблон:Cite book
  34. George, Henry (1905). Protection or Free Trade
  35. Шаблон:Cite book
  36. 36,0 36,1 36,2 36,3 Шаблон:Cite web
  37. 37,0 37,1 37,2 37,3 Шаблон:Cite web
  38. Шаблон:Cite book
  39. Шаблон:Cite book
  40. 40,0 40,1 Шаблон:Cite journal
  41. Шаблон:Cite web
  42. 42,0 42,1 42,2 42,3 Шаблон:Cite journal
  43. 43,0 43,1 43,2 43,3 Шаблон:Cite web
  44. Шаблон:Cite journal
  45. Шаблон:Cite book
  46. Шаблон:Cite web Address delivered on 18 February 1884 at the City Hall, Glasgow
  47. Шаблон:Cite journal
  48. Шаблон:Cite web
  49. Шаблон:Cite web
  50. Шаблон:Cite web
  51. Шаблон:Cite web
  52. Шаблон:Cite web
  53. Шаблон:Cite web
  54. Fox, Stephen R. The American Conservation Movement: John Muir and His Legacy. Madison, WI: U of Wisconsin, 1985.
  55. 55,0 55,1 55,2 Daly, Herman E., and Joshua C. Farley. Ecological Economics: Principles and Applications. Washington: Island, 2004.
  56. Шаблон:Cite web
  57. Шаблон:Cite web
  58. Шаблон:Cite web
  59. Шаблон:Cite journal
  60. Шаблон:Cite journal
  61. Шаблон:Cite web
  62. Шаблон:Cite book
  63. Шаблон:Cite book
  64. Шаблон:Cite news
  65. Шаблон:Cite web
  66. Шаблон:Cite web
  67. Socialism, Capitalism, and Geoism – by Lindy Davies
  68. Шаблон:LSJ.
  69. Шаблон:OEtymD
  70. Introduction to Earth Sharing,
  71. Шаблон:Cite web
  72. Шаблон:Cite web
  73. Шаблон:Cite web
  74. Шаблон:Cite web
  75. Шаблон:Cite web
  76. Шаблон:Cite web
  77. Шаблон:Cite web
  78. Шаблон:Cite web
  79. Шаблон:Cite web
  80. Шаблон:Cite book
  81. Шаблон:Cite news
  82. Шаблон:Cite web
  83. Шаблон:Citation
  84. Шаблон:Cite web
  85. Шаблон:Cite news
  86. Шаблон:Cite book
  87. Шаблон:Cite journal
  88. Шаблон:Cite web
  89. See https://academic.oup.com/qje/article-abstract/25/1/172/1908077 for more information on this Realty evaluation.
  90. City of Houston v. Baker
  91. Шаблон:Cite newsШаблон:Dead link
  92. Шаблон:Cite journal
  93. Шаблон:Cite web
  94. Шаблон:Cite news
  95. Шаблон:Cite news
  96. Шаблон:Cite web
  97. Шаблон:Cite news
  98. The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, vol. 62, 2003, p. 615
  99. Шаблон:Cite web
  100. Шаблон:Cite web
  101. Шаблон:Cite web
  102. Шаблон:Cite web
  103. Шаблон:Cite journal
  104. Шаблон:Cite book
  105. Шаблон:Cite web
  106. 106,0 106,1 Шаблон:Cite web
  107. Шаблон:Cite web
  108. Шаблон:Cite book
  109. Шаблон:Cite journal
  110. Шаблон:Cite book
  111. 111,0 111,1 Шаблон:Cite journal
  112. Шаблон:Cite book
  113. Шаблон:Cite book
  114. https://psmag.com/news/this-land-is-your-land-3392 "urban economics models actually do suggest that Georgist taxation would be the right approach at least to finance city growth."/
  115. Шаблон:Cite journal
  116. Шаблон:Cite web
  117. Шаблон:Cite journal
  118. Шаблон:Cite news
  119. Шаблон:Cite journal
  120. Шаблон:Cite book
  121. Шаблон:Cite web
  122. Шаблон:Cite book
  123. Шаблон:Cite web
  124. Шаблон:Cite journal Hayek wrote, "It was a lay enthusiasm for Henry George which led me to economics."
  125. Шаблон:Cite journal
  126. Шаблон:Cite book
  127. Шаблон:Cite book
  128. Шаблон:Cite book Supplemental Biography of John Rogers Commons: Chapter 19 of the online edition.
  129. Шаблон:Cite book
  130. Шаблон:Cite web
  131. Шаблон:Cite webШаблон:Cbignore
  132. Шаблон:Cite web
  133. Шаблон:Cite book
  134. Шаблон:Cite report
  135. Шаблон:Cite journal
  136. Шаблон:Cite web
  137. Шаблон:Cite web
  138. Шаблон:Cite web Excerpt: Prof. Friedman:... In my opinion, and this may come as a shock to some of you, the least bad tax is the property tax on the unimproved value of land, the Henry George argument of many, many years ago. "
  139. Шаблон:Cite web
  140. Шаблон:Cite web
  141. Airlie Worrall, The New Crusade: the Origins, Activities and Influence of the Australian Single Tax Leagues, 1889–1895 (M.A. thesis, University of Melbourne, 1978).
  142. Turgeon, Lynn. Bastard Keynesianism : the evolution of economic thinking and policymaking since World War II. Westport, Conn: Praeger, 1997
  143. Gaffney, Mason. "Warm Memories of Bill Vickrey". Land & Liberty. http://www.cooperative-individualism.org/gaffney-mason_warm-memories-of-bill-vickrey-1997.htm Шаблон:Webarchive
  144. Gaffney, Mason, and Fred Harrison. The corruption of economics. London: Shepheard-Walwyn in association with Centre for Incentive Taxation, 2006
  145. Шаблон:Cite journal
  146. Шаблон:Cite book
  147. Шаблон:Cite news
  148. Shoup, Donald C. "The Ideal Source of Local Public Revenue." Regional Science and Urban Economics 34.6 (2004): 753-84.
  149. Шаблон:Cite web
  150. Quotes from Nobel Prize Winners Herbert Simon stated in 1978: "Assuming that a tax increase is necessary, it is clearly preferable to impose the additional cost on land by increasing the land tax, rather than to increase the wage tax—the two alternatives open to the City (of Pittsburgh). It is the use and occupancy of property that creates the need for the municipal services that appear as the largest item in the budget—fire and police protection, waste removal, and public works. The average increase in tax bills of city residents will be about twice as great with wage tax increase than with a land tax increase."
  151. Шаблон:Cite web
  152. Шаблон:Cite web
  153. Шаблон:Cite web
  154. Шаблон:Cite journal
  155. Vickrey, William. "The Corporate Income Tax in the U.S. Tax System, 73 TAX NOTES 597, 603 (1996). Quote: "Removing almost all business taxes, including property taxes on improvements, excepting only taxes reflecting the marginal social cost of public services rendered to specific activities, and replacing them with taxes on site values, would substantially improve the economic efficiency of the jurisdiction."
  156. Шаблон:Cite journal
  157. Barker, Charles A., 1955. Henry George. New York: Oxford University Press
  158. Шаблон:Cite book
  159. Шаблон:Cite web
  160. Шаблон:Cite book
  161. Daunton, M. J. State and market in Victorian Britain : war, welfare and capitalism. Woodbridge, UK Rochester, NY: Boydell Press, 2008. Quote: "In the election of 1890 he campaigned for radical land reform, arguing for a tax on the 'unearned increment', and advocated the programme of Henry George as a means of 'bursting up the great estates'."
  162. "Winston S. Churchill / The Mother of all Monopolies -- 1909".
  163. Шаблон:Cite journal
  164. Шаблон:Cite news
  165. Stevens, Elizabeth Lesly. "A Tax Policy With San Francisco Roots". July 30, 2011 https://www.nytimes.com/2011/07/31/us/31bcstevens.html Quote: "But Mr. Brown was certainly in good company as a Georgist. Devotees over the years have included Leo Tolstoy, Winston Churchill, Sun Yat-Sen, and the inventor of the board game that would become Monopoly."
  166. Murdoch, Walter. Alfred Deakin: a sketch. Melbourne, Vic: Bookman, 1999. [1923]
  167. Шаблон:Cite book
  168. [George, Henry, Jr. The Life of Henry George. New York: Doubleday & McClure, 1900.]
  169. Шаблон:Cite web
  170. "Hughes, William Morris (Billy) (1862–1952)". Australian Dictionary of Biography: Online Edition.
  171. Шаблон:Cite news
  172. Шаблон:Cite journal
  173. Шаблон:Cite book
  174. Шаблон:Cite journal
  175. Шаблон:Cite book
  176. Chicago Single Tax Club collection, Special Collections and University Archives, University of Illinois at Chicago http://findingaids.library.uic.edu/ead/rjd1/ChiSingleTaxf.html
  177. 177,0 177,1 177,2 Шаблон:Cite web
  178. Шаблон:Cite book
  179. Шаблон:Cite journal
  180. Шаблон:Cite web
  181. Шаблон:Cite newsШаблон:Dead link
  182. Arnesen, Eric. Encyclopedia of U.S. Labor and Working-class History. New York: Routledge, 2007
  183. Johnston, Robert D. The Radical Middle Class: Populist Democracy and the Question of Capitalism in Progressive Era Portland, Oregon. Princeton, N.J: Princeton University Press, 2003
  184. Gaynor, William Jay. Some of Mayor Gaynor's Letters and Speeches. New York: Greaves Pub., 1913. 214–221. https://books.google.com/books?id=-7kMAAAAYAAJ&pg=PA219
  185. Howe, Frederic C. The Confessions of a Reformer. Kent, OH: Kent State UP, 1988.
  186. Arcas Cubero, Fernando: El movimiento georgista y los orígenes del Andalucismo : análisis del periódico "El impuesto único" (1911–1923). Málaga : Editorial Confederación Española de Cajas de Ahorros, 1980. Шаблон:ISBN
  187. "Single Taxers Dine Johnson". New York Times May 31, 1910.
  188. "Henry George". Ohio History Central: An Online History of Ohio History.
  189. Шаблон:Cite webШаблон:Cbignore
  190. Шаблон:Cite web
  191. Шаблон:Cite magazine
  192. Шаблон:Cite web
  193. Шаблон:Cite book
  194. Шаблон:Cite book
  195. Шаблон:Cite journal
  196. "Some Suggestions for Reform of Taxation", Proceedings, 14th Annual Convention, League of California Municipalities, Santa Barbara, California, October 25, 1911, pp. 152–171. J. Stitt Wilson, "Report from California", The Single Tax Review, V.17, No.1, January–February 1917, pp. 50–52
  197. 197,0 197,1 Шаблон:Cite book
  198. Шаблон:Cite magazine
  199. Шаблон:Cite journal
  200. Шаблон:Cite journal
  201. 201,0 201,1 Шаблон:Cite book
  202. Chris Oestereich. "With Liberty and Dividends for All: An Interview with Peter Barnes"; https://medium.com/@costrike/with-liberty-and-dividends-for-all-an-interview-with-peter-barnes-2d3cbd95028c
  203. Beth Shalom Hessel. "Field, Sara Bard"; http://www.anb.org/articles/15/15-00220.html; American National Biography Online April 2014. Access Date: Mar 22 2015
  204. Lane, Fintan. The Origins of Modern Irish Socialism, 1881–1896.Cork University Press, 1997 (pp. 79, 81).
  205. Шаблон:Cite journal
  206. Шаблон:Cite book
  207. Leubuscher, F. C. (1939). Bolton Hall Шаблон:Webarchive. The Freeman. January issue.
  208. Шаблон:Cite book
  209. Шаблон:Cite book
  210. Шаблон:Cite web Holmes said, "The passing years have only added to my conviction that Henry George is one of the greatest of all modern statesmen and prophets."
  211. Шаблон:Cite web
  212. Thompson, Noel. Political economy and the Labour Party: The economics of démocratic socialism (1884–2005). Routlegde Ed., 2006, pp. 54–55.
  213. Шаблон:Cite book
  214. Orr, B. S. (2006–2007). Mary Elizabeth Lease: Gendered discourse and Populist Party politics in Gilded Age America. Kansas History: A Journal of the Central Plains, 29, 246–265.
  215. Caves, Roger W. Encyclopedia of the City. Abingdon, Oxon, OX: Routledge, 2005.
  216. Marsh, Benjamin Clarke. Lobbyist for the People; a Record of Fifty Years. Washington: Public Affairs, 1953.
  217. Шаблон:Cite news
  218. Jorgensen, Emil Oliver. The next Step toward Real Democracy: One Hundred Reasons Why America Should Abolish, as Speedily as Possible, All Taxation upon the Fruits of Industry, and Raise the Public Revenue by a Single Tax on Land Values Only. Chicago, IL: Chicago Singletax Club, 1920.
  219. 220,0 220,1 Gorgas, William Crawford, and Lewis Jerome Johnson. Two Papers on Public Sanitation and the Single Tax. New York: Single Tax Information Bureau, 1914. https://books.google.com/books?id=v3NHAAAAYAAJ
  220. 221,0 221,1 Ware, Louise. George Foster Peabody, Banker, Philanthropist, Publicist. Athens: U of Georgia, 1951. http://dlg.galileo.usg.edu/ugapressbks/pdfs/ugp9780820334561.pdf
  221. Шаблон:Cite book
  222. Шаблон:Cite book
  223. Шаблон:Cite book "It would be far easier to levy a "single tax," basing it upon land values." "It is because ... a single land tax would prove to be the very essence of equity, that l advocate it.
  224. Шаблон:Cite book
  225. Шаблон:Cite book
  226. Шаблон:Cite book
  227. Шаблон:Cite web
  228. Шаблон:Cite journal
  229. Шаблон:Cite journal
  230. Шаблон:Cite web
  231. 232,0 232,1 232,2 Шаблон:Cite news
  232. Шаблон:Cite book
  233. Archived at GhostarchiveШаблон:Cbignore and the Wayback MachineШаблон:Cbignore: Шаблон:Cite webШаблон:Cbignore
  234. Шаблон:Cite web
  235. Шаблон:Cite journal
  236. Шаблон:Cite book
  237. Шаблон:Cite book
  238. Шаблон:Cite book
  239. Harrison, F. (May–June 1989). "Aldous Huxley on 'the Land Question' Шаблон:Webarchive". Land & Liberty. "Huxley redeems himself when he concedes that, if he were to rewrite the book, he would offer a third option, one which he characterised as 'the possibility of sanity.' In a few bold strokes he outlines the elements of this model: 'In this community economics would be decentralist and Henry Georgian, politics Kropotkinesque and co-operative.'"
  240. Шаблон:Cite book
  241. Шаблон:Cite book
  242. Шаблон:Cite web
  243. Шаблон:Cite web
  244. Lora, Ronald; Longton, William Henry, eds. (1999). The Conservative Press in Twentieth-century America. Greenwood Publishing, Inc. p. 310. "Thus, the Freeman was to speak for the great tradition of classical liberalism, which [Albert Jay Nock and Francis Nielson] were afraid was being lost, and for the economics of Henry George, which both men shared."
  245. Шаблон:Cite web
  246. Шаблон:Cite webSinclair was an active georgist but eventually gave up on explicitly advocating the reform because, "Our opponents, the great rich bankers and land speculators of California, persuaded the poor man that we were going to put all taxes on this poor man's lot."
  247. Шаблон:Cite web
  248. Шаблон:Cite book
  249. A Great Iniquity.. Leo Tolstoy once said of George, "People do not argue with the teaching of George, they simply do not know it".
  250. Шаблон:Cite web
  251. Шаблон:Cite book Wood had "strong leanings toward the single-tax theory of Henry George".
  252. Шаблон:Cite web
  253. Шаблон:Cite web
  254. Шаблон:Cite web
  255. Шаблон:Cite web
  256. Шаблон:Cite journal
  257. Шаблон:Cite web Buckley says, "The location problem is, of course, easily solved by any Georgist, and I am one."
  258. Шаблон:Cite book
  259. 260,0 260,1 Шаблон:Cite web
  260. Шаблон:Cite news
  261. Шаблон:Cite newsKinsley reiterates that George is his favorite economist and that land taxes are the best source of revenue.
  262. Шаблон:Cite web In The New Republic (February 12, 1992) Kinsley advocates removing all taxes and collecting land rent instead.
  263. Шаблон:Cite book
  264. Шаблон:Cite journal
  265. Шаблон:Cite news
  266. Шаблон:Cite tweet Dylan Matthews's verified account states, "I think we've both been Georgists for a while now."
  267. Шаблон:Cite book
  268. Шаблон:Cite book
  269. Riis, Jacob A. "The Unemployed: a Problem". (In Peters, John P., Labor and Capital, a chapter on "Socialism and the Single Tax", pp. 425-431. New York, 1902. 12°. Questions of the day, no. 98.)
  270. Шаблон:Cite book
  271. Шаблон:Cite news
  272. Шаблон:Cite journal
  273. Шаблон:Cite news
  274. Шаблон:Cite news
  275. Шаблон:Cite tweet
  276. Шаблон:Cite journal
  277. Шаблон:Cite book
  278. Miller, Joseph Dana (ed.), 1917. Single Tax Year Book. NY: Single Tax Review Publishing Company
  279. Шаблон:Cite news
  280. Шаблон:Cite journal
  281. Шаблон:Cite web
  282. Wineapple, Brenda. Sister Brother: Gertrude and Leo Stein. Lincoln: U of Nebraska, 2008.
  283. 284,0 284,1 Mills, Allen. "Single Tax, Socialism and the Independent Labour Party of Manitoba: The Political Ideas of F.J. Dixon and S.J. Farmer." Labour / Le Travail 5 (1980): 33–56. JSTOR. Weborn 04 Dec. 2014. <https://www.jstor.org/stable/10.2307/25139947?ref=no-x-route:ace15c2e1d6b230b7bafc46e82f39f89>
  284. Шаблон:Cite book
  285. Шаблон:Cite web
  286. J. R. LeMaster, James Darrell Wilson, C. G. H. (1903). The Mark Twain Encyclopedia.
  287. Muse return with new album The Resistance "Sure, he has already launched into a passionate soliloquy about Geoism (the land-tax movement inspired by the 19th-century political economist Henry George)".
  288. Шаблон:Cite book
  289. Co-founder of the Henry George Club, Australia.
  290. Шаблон:Cite web
  291. Шаблон:Cite web
  292. Шаблон:Cite web
  293. Шаблон:Cite book Author of "The New Colossus", on the Statue of Liberty, and the poem "Progress and Poverty", named after George's book, of which she said, "The life and thought of no one capable of understanding it can be quite the same after reading it."
  294. Шаблон:Cite journal Lazarus "supported Henry George's single tax".
  295. Шаблон:Cite web
  296. Шаблон:Cite book
  297. Шаблон:Cite book
  298. Шаблон:Cite book
  299. Шаблон:Cite book
  300. "Henry George, The Scholar" Шаблон:Webarchive – A Commencement Address Delivered by Francis Neilson at the Henry George School of Social Science, June 3, 1940.
  301. Шаблон:Cite journal
  302. Шаблон:Cite web
  303. McQueen, Humphrey. A New Britannia. St. Lucia, Qld.: U of Queensland, 2004.
  304. Шаблон:Cite journal
  305. Шаблон:Cite book
  306. Шаблон:Cite web
  307. Шаблон:Cite web
  308. Шаблон:Cite book
  309. Шаблон:Cite journal
  310. Шаблон:Cite journal
  311. Шаблон:Cite web
  312. Шаблон:Cite web
  313. Шаблон:Cite web
  314. Шаблон:Cite book
  315. Шаблон:Cite web
  316. Onken, Werner. "The Political Economy of Silvio Gesell: A Century of Activism." American Journal of Economics and Sociology 59.4 (2000): 609–622. Weborn 16 Aug. 2014.
  317. Шаблон:Cite web
  318. Шаблон:Cite web
  319. Шаблон:Cite book
  320. Шаблон:Cite book
  321. Шаблон:Cite book
  322. Шаблон:Cite book
  323. Шаблон:Cite web Letter addressed to a Mr. Krumreig
  324. Vallentyne, Peter. Left-libertarianism: A Primer. In Vallentyne, Peter; Steiner, Hillel (2000). "Left-libertarianism and Its Critics: The Contemporary Debate". Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire: Palgrave Publishers Ltd. "Georgist libertarians—such as eponymous George (1879, 1892), Steiner (1977, 1980, 1981, 1992, 1994), and Tideman (1991, 1997, 1998)—hold that agents may appropriate unappropriated natural resources as long as they pay for the competitive value of the rights they claim."
  325. Yarvin, Curtis, Good government as good customer service
  326. Yarvin, Curtis, Against political freedom
  327. Шаблон:Cite web
  328. Шаблон:Cite news
  329. Шаблон:Cite book
  330. Шаблон:Cite web Brandeis said, "I find it very difficult to disagree with the principles of Henry George... I believe in the taxation of land values only."
  331. How to Abolish Unfair Taxation: An Address Before a Los Angeles Audience, Delivered March 1913 https://books.google.com/books?id=rlOFHAAACAAJ
  332. Шаблон:Cite web
  333. Шаблон:Cite journal
  334. Two letters written in 1934 to Henry George's daughter, Anna George De Mille Шаблон:Webarchive. In one letter Einstein writes, "The spreading of these works is a really deserving cause, for our generation especially has many and important things to learn from Henry George."
  335. Шаблон:Cite news
  336. Шаблон:Cite news Henry Ford says that "every American family can have a piece of land. We ought to tax all idle land the way Henry George said—tax it heavily, so that its owners would have to make it productive."
  337. Шаблон:Cite journal
  338. Шаблон:Cite journal
  339. Шаблон:Cite web
  340. Шаблон:Cite webШаблон:Cbignore
  341. Шаблон:Cite web
  342. Magie invented The Landlord's Game, predecessor to Monopoly
  343. Шаблон:Cite web
  344. Шаблон:Cite web
  345. Шаблон:Cite news
  346. Шаблон:Cite book
  347. Шаблон:Cite book
  348. Шаблон:Cite news
  349. Шаблон:Cite web
  350. Шаблон:Cite book Wallace described Progress and Poverty as "Undoubtedly the most remarkable and important book of the present century."
  351. Шаблон:Cite book