Английская Википедия:Economic results of migration

Материал из Онлайн справочника
Перейти к навигацииПерейти к поиску

Шаблон:Short description Various effects of migration have been an area of study and debate amongst economists. Researchers have studied questions including: if migrants hurt wages for natives; what is their tax contribution/burden; what are the effects of the money migrants send home (remittances); and how does the loss of workers affect the sender country (brain drain).

Research into migration may be politically consequential, researchers noting that migration may be viewed by the public as a fiscal burden, or a cure to economic ills[1][2]

Impact on native country

There is extensive[3] research into migration, researchers having studied its effect on metrics such as unemployment, productivity, wages, and government spending.

On natives in general: Immigration economists David Card, Christian Dustmann, and Ian Preston claim "most existing studies of the economic impacts of immigration suggest these impacts are small, and on average benefit the native population".[4] Similar conclusions were found in other studies and literature reviews.[5][1][6][7][8]

Effects may vary due to factors like the migrants' age, education, reason for migration,[1] the strength of the economy, and how long ago the migration took place.[6]

Research also suggests that cultural diversity has a net positive effect on the productivity of natives.[8]

It is argued that migrants face significant barriers before immigrating, like having sufficient funds, social support, personal motivation, education, and qualifications. Such a filter may enhance their economic contribution in contrast from a random section of their home population.[2]

On low-skilled natives: Conventional models say that that low-skilled natives are especially vulnerable to migration because they face a more competitive labour market.[3] However, studies show small and mixed impacts.[3][9][10][1][11][12][13]

On other migrants: A UK study found that migration reduced the wages of already-present migrants but not natives. It suggests this is due to a lack of substitutability from the migrants since they were better educated than the native population. This difference meant natives and migrants did not compete for the same roles.[14]

By refugees: Studies of refugees' impact on native welfare are scantШаблон:Needs update but the existing literature also shows mixed results (negative, positive and no significant effects on native welfare).[3][15][16][17][18][19][20][21][22]

By undocumented migrants: Research on the economic effects of undocumented immigrants is even more scantШаблон:Needs update but existing studies suggest that the effects are positive for the native population.[23][24] A 2015 study shows that "increasing deportation rates and tightening border control weakens low-skilled labor markets, increasing unemployment of native low-skilled workers. Legalization, instead, decreases the unemployment rate of low-skilled natives and increases income per native."[10]

United States

A survey of economists shows a consensus behind the view that high-skilled immigration makes the average American better off.[25] A survey of the same economists also shows strong support behind the notion that low-skilled immigration makes the average American better off.[26]

Overall immigration has not had much effect on native wage inequality[27] but low-skill immigration has been linked to greater income inequality in the native population.[28] According to labor economist Giovanni Peri, the existing literature suggests that there are no economic reasons why the American labor market could not easily absorb 100,000 Syrian refugees in a year.[29][30]

Study methodologies

David Card's 1990 work[31] is considered a landmark study in the topic. It followed the Mariel boatlift, a natural experiment when 125,000 Cubans (Marielitos) came to Miami after a sudden relaxation in emigration rules. It lacked the limitations of previous studies, including that migrants often choose high-wage cities, so increases in wages could simply be a result of the economic success of the city rather than the migrants. But the Marielitos chose Miami simply because it was near Cuba rather than for lucrative wages. Preceding studies were also limited in that firms and natives may respond to migration and its effects by moving to more lucrative areas. But the six-month period of this migration was too brief for most firms or individuals to leave Miami.[2][32]

Another natural experiment followed a group of Czech workers who, shortly after the fall of the Berlin wall, were suddenly able to work in Germany though they continued to live in Czechia. It found significant declines in native wages and employment as a result.[33] It is argued migrants must also spend their wages in the employing country in order to stimulate the economy and offset their impacts.[2]

Impact on the migrants and global poverty

Research suggests that migration is beneficial both to the receiving and sending countries.[34] According to one study, welfare increases in both types of countries: "welfare impact of observed levels of migration is substantial, at about 5% to 10% for the main receiving countries and about 10% in countries with large incoming remittances".[34] Studies show that the elimination of barriers to migration would have profound effects on world GDP, with estimates of gains ranging between 67 and 147%.[35][36][37] According to Branko Milanovic, country of residency is by far the most important determinant of global income inequality, which suggests that the reduction in labor barriers would significantly reduce global income inequality.[38][39] A study of equivalent workers in the United States and 42 developing countries found that "median wage gap for a male, unskilled (9 years of schooling), 35 year-old, urban formal sector worker born and educated in a developing country is P$15,400 per year at purchasing power parity".[40] A 2014 survey of the existing literature on emigration finds that a 10 percent emigrant supply shock would increase wages in the sending country by 2–5.5%.[41] According to economists Michael Clemens and Lant Pratchett, "permitting people to move from low-productivity places to high-productivity places appears to be by far the most efficient generalized policy tool, at the margin, for poverty reduction".[42] A successful two-year in situ anti-poverty program, for instance, helps poor people make in a year what is the equivalent of working one day in the developed world.[42] Research on a migration lottery that allowed Tongans to move to New Zealand found that the lottery winners saw a 263% increase in income from migrating (after only one year in New Zealand) relative to the unsuccessful lottery entrants.[43] A longer-term study on the Tongan lottery winners finds that they "continue to earn almost 300 percent more than non-migrants, have better mental health, live in households with more than 250 percent higher expenditure, own more vehicles, and have more durable assets".[44] A conservative estimate of their lifetime gain to migration is NZ$315,000 in net present value terms (approximately US$237,000).[44] A slight reduction in the barriers to labor mobility between the developing and developed world would do more to reduce poverty in the developing world than any remaining trade liberalization.[45]

Impact on trade and innovation

Research also finds that migration leads to greater trade in goods and services.[46][47] Using 130 years of data on historical migrations to the United States, one study finds "that a doubling of the number of residents with ancestry from a given foreign country relative to the mean increases by 4.2 percentage points the probability that at least one local firm invests in that country, and increases by 31% the number of employees at domestic recipients of FDI from that country. The size of these effects increases with the ethnic diversity of the local population, the geographic distance to the origin country, and the ethno-linguistic fractionalization of the origin country."[48] Mass migration can also boost innovation and growth,[49][50] as shown by the Huguenot diaspora in Prussia,[51] German Jewish emigration to the United States.[52] Immigrants have been linked to greater invention and innovation in the U.S.[53] Research also shows that labor migration increases human capital.[54] Foreign doctoral students are a major source of innovation in the American economy.[55]

Impact on the sending country

Remittances increase living standards in the country of origin. Remittances are a large share of the GDP of many developing countries.[56] A study on remittances to Mexico found that remittances lead to a substantial increase in the availability of public services in Mexico, surpassing government spending in some localities.[57]

Research finds that emigration and low migration barriers has net positive effects on human capital formation in the sending countries.[54][58][59][60] There was found to be a "brain gain", instead of a "brain drain", because of emigration.

One study finds that sending countries benefit indirectly in the long run on the emigration of skilled workers because those skilled workers are able to innovate more in developed countries, which the sending countries are able to benefit on as a positive externality. Greater emigration of skilled workers consequently leads to greater economic growth and welfare improvements in the long-run.[61] The negative effects of high-skill emigration remain largely unfounded. According to economist Michael Clemens, it has not been shown that restrictions on high-skill emigration reduce shortages in the countries of origin.[62]

Research also suggests that emigration, remittances and return migration can have a positive impact on political institutions and democratization in the country of origin.[63][64][65][66][67][68][69][70] Research also shows that remittances can lower the risk of civil war in the country of origin.[71] Return migration from countries with liberal gender norms has been associated with the transfer of liberal gender norms to the home country.[72]

Research suggests that emigration causes an increase in the wages of those who remain in the country of origin. A 2014 survey of the existing literature on emigration finds that a 10 percent emigrant supply shock would increase wages in the sending country by 2–5.5%.[41] A study of emigration from Poland shows that it led to a slight increase in wages for high- and medium-skilled workers for remaining Poles.[73] A 2013 study finds that emigration from Eastern Europe after the 2004 EU enlargement increased the wages of remaining young workers in the country of origin by 6%, while it had no effect on the wages of old workers.[74] The wages of Lithuanian men increased as a result of emigration after the Lithuanian accession to the European Union in 2004.[75] Return migration is associated with greater household firm revenues.[76]

Some research shows that the remittance effect is not strong enough to make the remaining natives in countries with high emigration flows better off.[77]

It has been argued that high-skill emigration causes labour shortages in the country of origin. This remains unsupported in the academic literature though.Шаблон:Citation needed

Political philosopher Adam James Tebble argues that more open borders aid both the economic and institutional development of poorer migrant sending countries, contrary to proponents of "brain-drain" critiques of migration.[78][79]

Push factors and pull factors

Push factors

Push factors are reasons that push people away from their countries. Examples of push factors are:

  • political fears
  • not enough jobs
  • few opportunities
  • natural disasters
  • wars
  • unhappy life
  • shortage of food
  • Insecurity
  • scarcity of land etc.

Pull factors

Pull factors are reasons that pull people to other countries. Examples of pull factors are:

  • A better way of life
  • Chances of a job
  • Improved living conditions
  • Education
  • Better housing
  • Medical care
  • Family links
  • Religious freedom
  • Fertile land

See also

References

Шаблон:Reflist

Further reading

  1. 1,0 1,1 1,2 1,3 Шаблон:Cite journal
  2. 2,0 2,1 2,2 2,3 Шаблон:Cite book
  3. 3,0 3,1 3,2 3,3 Шаблон:Cite journal
  4. Шаблон:Cite journal
  5. Шаблон:Cite book
  6. 6,0 6,1 Шаблон:Cite web
  7. Шаблон:Cite journal
  8. 8,0 8,1 Шаблон:Cite journal
  9. Шаблон:Cite journal
  10. 10,0 10,1 Шаблон:Cite journal
  11. Шаблон:Cite journal
  12. Шаблон:Cite journal
  13. Шаблон:Cite journal
  14. Шаблон:Cite journal
  15. Шаблон:Cite web
  16. Шаблон:Cite web
  17. Шаблон:Cite book
  18. Шаблон:Cite journal
  19. Шаблон:Cite web
  20. Шаблон:Cite web
  21. Шаблон:Cite journal
  22. Шаблон:Cite web
  23. Шаблон:Cite journal
  24. Шаблон:Cite journal
  25. Шаблон:Cite web
  26. Шаблон:Cite web
  27. Шаблон:Cite journal
  28. Шаблон:Cite journal
  29. Шаблон:Cite journal
  30. Шаблон:Cite web
  31. Шаблон:Cite journal
  32. Шаблон:Cite journal
  33. Шаблон:Cite journal
  34. 34,0 34,1 Шаблон:Cite journal
  35. Шаблон:Cite journal
  36. Шаблон:Cite journal
  37. Шаблон:Cite journal
  38. Шаблон:Cite journal
  39. Шаблон:Cite news
  40. Шаблон:Cite journal
  41. 41,0 41,1 Шаблон:Cite book
  42. 42,0 42,1 Шаблон:Cite web
  43. Шаблон:Cite journal
  44. 44,0 44,1 Шаблон:Cite journal
  45. Шаблон:Cite journal
  46. Шаблон:Cite web
  47. Шаблон:Cite journal
  48. Шаблон:Cite journal
  49. Шаблон:Cite journal
  50. Шаблон:Cite web
  51. Шаблон:Cite journal
  52. Шаблон:Cite journal
  53. Шаблон:Cite journal
  54. 54,0 54,1 Шаблон:Cite journal
  55. Шаблон:Cite journal
  56. Шаблон:Cite journal
  57. Шаблон:Cite journal
  58. Шаблон:Cite journal
  59. Шаблон:Cite journal
  60. Шаблон:Cite journal
  61. Шаблон:Cite web
  62. Шаблон:Cite journal
  63. Шаблон:Cite journal
  64. Шаблон:Cite journal
  65. Шаблон:Cite web
  66. Шаблон:Cite web
  67. Шаблон:Cite journal
  68. Шаблон:Cite web
  69. Шаблон:Cite journal
  70. Шаблон:Cite journal
  71. Шаблон:Cite journal
  72. Шаблон:Cite journal
  73. Шаблон:Cite journal
  74. Шаблон:Cite journal
  75. Шаблон:Cite journal
  76. Шаблон:Cite web
  77. Шаблон:Cite journal
  78. Шаблон:Cite journal
  79. Шаблон:Cite journal