Английская Википедия:Growth imperative

Материал из Онлайн справочника
Перейти к навигацииПерейти к поиску

Шаблон:Short description

Файл:World GDP per capita 1500 to 2003.svg
The role of growth imperatives for the increase in the global gross domestic product per capita is disputed.

Growth imperative is a term in economic theory regarding a possible necessity of economic growth. On the micro level, it describes mechanisms that force firms or consumers (households) to increase revenues or consumption to not endanger their income. On the macro level, a political growth imperative exists if economic growth is necessary to avoid economic and social instability or to retain democratic legitimacy, so that other political goals such as climate change mitigation or a reduction of inequality are subordinated to growth policies.[1][2]

Current neoclassical, Keynesian and endogenous growth theories do not consider a growth imperative[3] or explicitly deny it, such as Robert Solow.[4] In neoclassical economics, adherence to economic growth would be a question of maximizing utility, an intertemporal decision between current and future consumption (see Keynes–Ramsey rule).[5] Other sociological and political theories consider several possible causes for pursuing economic growth, for example maximizing profit, social comparison, culture (conformity), or political ideologies, but they do not regard them to be compulsive. Possible growth imperatives are discussed in Marxist theory, Schumpeterian theory of creative destruction and ecological economics, as well as in political debates on post-growth and degrowth.[6] It is disputed whether growth imperative is a meaningful concept altogether, who would be affected by it, and which mechanism would be responsible.[1]

Meaning and definitions

At the macroeconomic or political level, the concept of growth imperatives is used by some authors when there seems to be no acceptable political alternative to economic growth,[7] because insufficient growth would lead to economic and social instability[8] up to "severe economic crises".[9] The alternative to growth would not be a stable stationary economy, but uncontrolled shrinkage.[10][11] The consequences of a renunciation of growth would be inacceptable so that growth appears politically without alternative.[1] While some search for purely "structural theoretical explanations for the commitment to growth",[12] others argue that this macroeconomic phenomenon must be examined at the micro level in line with methodological individualism to explain how and why individual actors (firms, consumers) act and how this interacts with collective structures, and correspondingly study the growth of enterprises with microeconomics and business administration and the increase of consumption using consumption sociology or consumer choice theory.[1][13]

The discussion on growth imperatives is part of a standing debate over the primacy of structure or agency in shaping human behavior. In the social sciences the term social coercion is used when situation-related circumstances[14] or strong social pressure[15] determine the behaviour.[1] According to Marxist theory, a coercion for firms to "grow or die" is due to economic competition.[16][17] According to these Marxists, capitalism "cannot stand still, but must always be either expanding or contracting".[18] Similarly, the environmental economist Шаблон:Ill speaks of a growth imperative for firms only when they are existentially threatened by steadily declining profits and ultimately bankruptcy; in other cases he uses the weaker term growth driver.[10][19][20][21][22] These definitions can be summarized that a growth imperative exists if exterior conditions make it necessary for agents to increase their economic efforts as to avoid existential consequences.[1]

Microeconomic theories

Firms

Файл:Marx - Das Kapital - 1867 - DHM retusche.jpg
Das Kapital by Karl Marx contains the first theory of a growth imperative, which is still disputed today.

The first theory of a growth imperative is attributed[5] to Karl Marx. In capitalism, zero growth is not possible, because of the mechanisms of competition and accumulation.[23][24][25]

Шаблон:Quote

Therefore, a company's growth is considered necessary to ensure the survival of the company ("grow or die"[16][17]): "investment is not an option, or a discretionary decision, it is an imperative that constrains every capitalists' actions and governs the overall economy"[26] Correspondingly, some authors argue that the compulsion to grow can only be defused by overcoming structures of market economies, or by pushing back profit-oriented companies that impropriate the surplus value.[16][17][27][28][29][30] Other authors Шаблон:Who criticize this Marxist perspective: a company could be profitable without growth if a positive accounting profit is distributed as dividend to the owners. Only if net income had to be retained, companies would be compelled to grow.[1][2][31] If a company shows an accounting profit, it has not yet achieved an economic profit in the economic sense, because a return on equity and an entrepreneurial salary would have to be paid from it - the profit would not necessarily be available for growth. Therefore, a market economy with profit-oriented companies is compatible with zero growth, as it is in the models of neoclassical theory (→ zero-profit condition).[1][3][32]

Файл:Factory Automation Robotics Palettizing Bread.jpg
The link between technical progress and resource use is disputed

On the basis of concepts of evolutionary economics, other authors point out that firms can become dependent on growth as a result of certain economic conditions. Joseph Schumpeter[33] had described the creative destruction in which the existence of firms is endangered if they cannot keep up with the innovation competition. This is interpreted as a need to invest in new technologies and to expand production[8][31][34] - but which investments would be necessary can only be understood in the light of growth theory. Within neoclassical growth accounting it is largely undisputed that only technological change and new combinations of factors of production make sustainable growth of firms and per capita income possible.[3][35][36] However, the contribution of single production factors to economic growth has been disputed for decades:[1][37] While endogenous growth theory concentrates on the role of human capital (ideas, education, innovations),[38][39] proponents of ecological or environmental economics emphasize the importance of energy consumption as well as raw materials, which are often non-renewable resources (e.g. fossil fuels).[40][41][42][43] While from the human capital perspective no ecologically damaging growth imperative arises, the resource perspective emphasizes that raw material consumption is lucrative for firms because it allows them to substitute expensive labour with cheaper machines. Accordingly, they would constantly invest in new resource-intensive technologies plus the human capital needed for development, which increases resource consumption and compensates advances in energy efficiency (rebound effects).[1][44]

There is also disagreement as to whether these dependencies can be overcome at the company level - provided that this is desired by the owners or the management. Proposals include new management practices, changes in product range, supply chains and distribution channels,[8][45] as well as the creation of solidarity enterprises, collective enterprises[3][29] and cooperatives.[46][47] Other authors call for institutional solutions: reforms of corporate law to overcome the legal constraint of public limited companies to maximise profits,[48] reforms of competition law to prevent externalisation at the expense of common goods,[49] or an institutional limitation of resource consumption and/or increasing their costs through ecotaxes or emissions trading (Cap and Trade), so that technical innovations would put a stronger focus on resource productivity instead of labour productivity.[1][34]

Private households

Файл:Hand held phones.JPG
Smart phone and car: voluntary consumption or necessary increases of individual productivity?

An imperative for private households to increase their income and consumption expenditure is rarely discussed.[50] In neoclassical household theory, households try to maximize their utility, whereby, in contrast to the profit maximization of firms, they are not subject to market imperatives.[1] Therefore, a growth imperative is usually not assumed here, but rather a free decision between current and future consumption.[5] This "intertemporal optimization" is represented, for example, by the Keynes-Ramsey rule.[51] In consumption sociology various theories of consumer society examine the influence of social norms on consumption decisions. Examples are conspicuous consumption, which was addressed as early as 1899 by Thorstein Veblen in his book The Theory of the Leisure Class,[52] or competition with positional goods, which was described by Fred Hirsch in 1976 in the book Social Limits to Growth.[53] Some authors claim that comparison with others and the unfair distribution of income and power would lead to a growth imperative for consumers: Consumers would have to work and consume more and more in order to achieve a minimum level of social participation,[54] because the economically weak are stigmatised.[55] The reasons given for this behaviour are fear and powerlessness, guilt and shame. However, whether these theories can actually justify a compulsion to increase consumption is disputed, as long as it is not a matter of securing one's livelihood (for example because of unemployment).[1][56]

Another line of argument views certain consumption decisions rather as investments for future growth,[57] but sometimes to increase one's own productivity.[50] Technical products such as vehicles, kitchen appliances or smartphones were used to save time and retain opportunities to earn an income. Over time, these goods would become a necessity, therefore a compulsion to increase one's consumption expenditure could be derived in order to not be left behind technically and economically.[1]

Macroeconomic theories

Political resp. macroeconomic growth imperative

Файл:Sustainable Development Goal 08DecentWork.svg
Economic growth is part of goal 8 of the Sustainable Development Goals

Economic growth has been formulated as an important economic policy goal for decades.[58][59] Examples include the "growth duty" in British legislation,[60] but also the Canadian Jobs and Growth Act, the African Growth and Opportunity Act or the European Stability and Growth Pact of 1997. This has been criticised as politically adhering to a dogma or ideology by some critics of growth.[61][62][63]

The theory of a political growth imperative, on the other hand, argues that economic growth would be necessary to avoid economic or social instability and to retain democratic legitimacy, or to guarantee national security and international competition.[1][2] Some authors stress that public finances[64] or social insurance systems such as unemployment insurance or pensions are dependent on growth.[56][65] Raghuram Rajan sees the cause primarily in political promises that are inherent to social systems.[66] Unemployment, which would occur in the event of technical progress and simultaneous lack of economic growth, is identified as a central problem (Okun's law).[1][67][68][69] Thus, growth above the employment threshold is repeatedly called for in political debates, in order to reduce unemployment.[62] Growth enhancing state investment, but also numerous incentives for private investment would not be simply politician's free will but indispensable to prevent social instability through mass unemployment.[1] This situation would be aggravated by international competition and free trade.[59]

As a way out, a redirection of technological development with the help of resource taxes is discussed (ecotax, emissions trading),[48][70] but also a general reduction of working time to reduce unemployment.[71][72][73] At the same time, a more equal distribution of income is demanded, either by fighting the privatisation of economic rents such as land rent or resource rent (→ rentier state),[1][74][75] or by calling for an unconditional basic income.[73]

Monetary system and the role of positive interest rates

For a long time,[76] several authors especially from German-speaking countries[77] have been locating a macroeconomic growth imperative in the monetary system, especially due to the combination of credit money and compound interest. This is considered to lead inevitably and system-immanently to an exponential growth of debt and interest-bearing deposits.[78][79][80] Some proponents of post-growth would derive a general criticism of positive interest rates from that and support ideas such as demurrage on currency, a concept from Freiwirtschaft,[76][81][82][83][84] or full-reserve banking.[85]

A second line of argument goes back to Шаблон:Ill, his doctoral student Guido Beltrani,[86] and his son Шаблон:Ill.[87][88] They argue[89] that "a portion of money is constantly removed from circulation" by banks[90] which is mainly responsible for the growth imperative.[91][92] In his book The Growth Spiral (2013), Hans Christoph Binswanger estimated a necessary minimum growth rate to be 1.8 %, while Mathias Binswanger (2009)[92] derived a minimum growth rate of 0.45 %, such that enterprises can still generate profits in the aggregate. In his book Der Wachstumszwang (2019), this minimum rate is lowered to zero as to enable firms to accumulate profits.[93][94]

Файл:Njp506747f2 hr SFC model stability analysis.png
Numerical stability analysis of Stock-Flow consistent models. For certain parameter values (here: interest rate and consumption out of wealth), zero growth is unstable, but stable for others.[95]

Other authors criticise the results of Beltrani as well as H. C. and M. Binswanger on the basis that they are based on inconsistent economic models and therefore not valid (→ Stock-Flow consistent model).[96][97] Those models show how repaid interest is not simply 'removed' from circulation, but flows back into the economy where it can be earned and repeated used to service debts. Models such as those created by Jackson & Victor show that, if no money is accumulated, then all debt can be serviced, and hence that no growth imperative arises from the creation of money as debt, 'per se'. [98] This leads some theorists to conclude that the monetary growth imperative only applies for certain parameters in the consumption function.[29][89][99] They argue that ultimately it is not the interest rate but the savings rate that is decisive for the stability of a stationary economy. If any interest income is consumed in full by the lender, i.e., bank or creditor of the bank, it is available again for repayment. Whether a stationary state can be reached, therefore, depends on the saving decisions of those who earn income or own assets. For zero growth it would only be necessary that savings of some are balanced by consumption out of wealth by others[22][89][95] (→ life-cycle hypothesis). The assumption that banks must retain profits even in a non-growing economy would be unfounded.[89] Accordingly, there would be no grow imperative "inherent" to the monetary system, but zero growth would be impossible as long as actors decide to continuously accumulate financial assets.[100]

In neoclassical theory and all varieties that presuppose the neutrality of money (classical dichotomy), the money market has no long-term effects on real economic variables such as economic growth. A monetary growth imperative is already excluded here by assumption.[77][101][100] However, post-Keynesian authors who doubt the neutrality of money reject a monetary growth imperative as well.[95][99][102][103]

Political demands to overcome growth imperatives

In September 2018, more than 200 scientists asked the European Union to turn away from any growth imperative[104] – a similar demand was raised by the participants of the Шаблон:Ill[105][106] and the post-growth working group of attac Germany.[107] But even within the post-growth or degrowth movement, the existence of growth imperatives is disputed.[1][29] Among German parties, the demand was included in the political programmes of the Ecological Democratic Party[108] and Alliance 90/The Greens.[109] Green politicians such as Reinhard Loske[110] or Jürgen Trittin[111] call for overcoming growth imperatives. In a dissenting opinion on the final report of the Шаблон:Ill of the German parliament (Bundestag), the experts Michael Müller, Шаблон:Ill, Ulrich Brand, Шаблон:Ill and Шаблон:Ill, as well as the members of the Bundestag Шаблон:Ill and the parliamentary group Die Linke, argued that "the question must be answered as to whether progress that is innovative and integrative, socially just and ecologically sustainable is possible without any growth imperative".[112]

Literature

This article was translated from Wachstumszwang in the German Wikipedia which is based on:

References

Шаблон:Reflist

  1. 1,00 1,01 1,02 1,03 1,04 1,05 1,06 1,07 1,08 1,09 1,10 1,11 1,12 1,13 1,14 1,15 1,16 1,17 1,18 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок richters_contested не указан текст
  2. 2,0 2,1 2,2 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок ferguson2019 не указан текст
  3. 3,0 3,1 3,2 3,3 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок lange не указан текст
  4. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок solowstoll не указан текст
  5. 5,0 5,1 5,2 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок gordon не указан текст
  6. Шаблон:Cite web
  7. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок scherhorn не указан текст
  8. 8,0 8,1 8,2 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок paech не указан текст
  9. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок flotow не указан текст
  10. 10,0 10,1 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок binswanger_wachstumsspirale не указан текст
  11. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок binswoyn не указан текст
  12. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок ferguson119 не указан текст
  13. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок deutschmann_wsi не указан текст
  14. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок lane не указан текст
  15. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок sullivan не указан текст
  16. 16,0 16,1 16,2 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок smith не указан текст
  17. 17,0 17,1 17,2 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок foster не указан текст
  18. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок ferguson76 не указан текст
  19. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок spiral не указан текст
  20. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок seidl24 не указан текст
  21. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок mugier не указан текст
  22. 22,0 22,1 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок wenzlaff не указан текст
  23. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок radkau не указан текст
  24. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок marxde не указан текст
  25. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок marxen не указан текст
  26. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок pineault не указан текст
  27. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок blauwhof не указан текст
  28. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок karathan не указан текст
  29. 29,0 29,1 29,2 29,3 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок annrev не указан текст
  30. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок kallissoc не указан текст
  31. 31,0 31,1 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок lawn не указан текст
  32. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок richters_marktwirtschaft_49-59 не указан текст
  33. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок schump не указан текст
  34. 34,0 34,1 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок richters_marktwirtschaft_S96-116 не указан текст
  35. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок hulten не указан текст
  36. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок blanchard не указан текст
  37. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок stern1 не указан текст
  38. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок jones не указан текст
  39. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок rosen не указан текст
  40. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок kümmel не указан текст
  41. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок kümlind не указан текст
  42. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок ayreswarr не указан текст
  43. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок ozturk не указан текст
  44. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок grahl не указан текст
  45. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок reichel не указан текст
  46. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок posse не указан текст
  47. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок gebauer не указан текст
  48. 48,0 48,1 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок binswanger_vorwaerts не указан текст
  49. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок scherhorn129 не указан текст
  50. 50,0 50,1 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок siemoneit-offer не указан текст
  51. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок blanchard89 не указан текст
  52. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок veblen не указан текст
  53. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок hirsch не указан текст
  54. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок sturn не указан текст
  55. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок rogall-S131 не указан текст
  56. 56,0 56,1 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок paech_öwi не указан текст
  57. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок perrotta не указан текст
  58. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок schmelzerecol не указан текст
  59. 59,0 59,1 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок schmelzer_hegemony не указан текст
  60. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок growthduty не указан текст
  61. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок stratmann не указан текст
  62. 62,0 62,1 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок rivera не указан текст
  63. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок barry не указан текст
  64. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок seidlstaat не указан текст
  65. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок höpflinger не указан текст
  66. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок rajan не указан текст
  67. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок antal не указан текст
  68. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок antal2 не указан текст
  69. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок jacksongreen не указан текст
  70. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок richters_wege не указан текст
  71. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок D'Alisa не указан текст
  72. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок videira не указан текст
  73. 73,0 73,1 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок ferguson не указан текст
  74. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок richters_marktwirtschaft_S96-153 не указан текст
  75. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок stratford не указан текст
  76. 76,0 76,1 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок onken не указан текст
  77. 77,0 77,1 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок strunz1 не указан текст
  78. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок douthwaite не указан текст
  79. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок lietaer не указан текст
  80. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок walter не указан текст
  81. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок suhr не указан текст
  82. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок bender не указан текст
  83. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок creutz не указан текст
  84. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок kennedy не указан текст
  85. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок farley не указан текст
  86. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок beltrani не указан текст
  87. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок JPKE2009 не указан текст
  88. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок binschapter не указан текст
  89. 89,0 89,1 89,2 89,3 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок consistencyanalysis не указан текст
  90. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок spiral131 не указан текст
  91. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок wachstumsspirale131 не указан текст
  92. 92,0 92,1 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок binsJPKE не указан текст
  93. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок binswazwa275 не указан текст
  94. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок rezbins не указан текст
  95. 95,0 95,1 95,2 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок berg не указан текст
  96. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок gilanyi не указан текст
  97. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок johnson не указан текст
  98. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок jacksondoes не указан текст
  99. 99,0 99,1 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок lavoie не указан текст
  100. 100,0 100,1 Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок strunz не указан текст
  101. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок binswazwa не указан текст
  102. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок fontana не указан текст
  103. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок carnevali не указан текст
  104. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок wandelat не указан текст
  105. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок dgrosalux не указан текст
  106. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок dgprog не указан текст
  107. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок attac не указан текст
  108. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок oedp не указан текст
  109. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок gruene не указан текст
  110. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок loske не указан текст
  111. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок schulte не указан текст
  112. Ошибка цитирования Неверный тег <ref>; для сносок enquete не указан текст